LAIZER
EDWIN N
BAPRM
42691
Language
as a corporate asset
Although interest in
academic research of the economics of language is of recent origin, by the end
of the seventeenth century many philosophers already had started to recognize
the relationship between economics and language. Coulmas (1992: 2) observes,
‘The analogy of money and language which is so conspicuously encoded in
language itself has often been regarded as mere stylistic decoration.’ He
translates an example from the early seventeenth century thinker, Stefano
Guazzo, who used the analogy in making the point that in public speech the
valuable must be separated from the worthless, as follows: ‘Just as all sorts
of coins, golden, silver and copper issue from a purse, expressions and other
words of greater and lesser value come out of the speaker’s mouth’ (Coulmas,
1992: 2).
Late in the seventeenth
century, Locke referred to word as ‘the common measure of commerce and
communication’ (Locke, 1959: 154). Locke’s contemporary, Leibniz, alluded to
the link between language and money, drawing an analogy between words as aid to
thought and logic and counters as aid to computation (Leibniz, 1983: 5). He was
looking for precision in valuation through both linguistic nomenclature and
economic measurement. According to Coulmas (1992): Leibniz did not believe
that, as a matter of principle, the expressive power of one language was
greater than another. Nevertheless, he realized the advantage of precision. The
smaller the unit, the greater the exactitude of the transactions that can be
carried out in a system that uses it (Coulmas, 1992: 3).
A few decades later, Hume (1964) moved beyond
the metaphor. He saw parallels in the development and functions of language and
money: In like manner are languages gradually established by human conventions
without any promise. In like manner do gold and silver become the common
measures of exchange, and are esteemed sufficient payment for what is of a
hundred times their value’ (Coulmas, 1992: 3).
According to another seventeenth century
thinker, Adam Smith, the currency of a country ‘is the exact measure of the
real exchange able value of all commodities. It is so, however, at the same
time and place only’ (Smith, 1904: 39). Correspondingly, explains Coulmas
(1992: 4), ‘the value of words is contingent upon temporarily and locally limited
common practice’. Coulmas quotes Hamann, a contemporary of Smith, to make his
point:
Money and language are
two objects whose investigation is as profound and abstract as their use is
common. Both are more closely related to each other than should be conjectured.
The theory of the one explains that of the other; they seem to issue from
common grounds. The wealth of all human knowledge is based on the exchange of
words life, on the other hand, are related to money as their universal measure.
Coulmas (1992: 4) goes on to
explain that ‘words do not derive their meaning from their material substance but
from the purpose they serve in transmitting nonmaterial content, and likewise
the value of money is not based on its material embodiment, but on the function
it fulfils as a common means for the exchange of goods’.
No comments:
Post a Comment